As befits a nation more than one-half covered in ice, Canadian health care reform efforts -- including some very limited measures to open the door to both private insurers and private providers -- continue at a glacial pace, the NYT reports.
As befits a nation more than one-half covered in ice, Canadian health care reform efforts -- including some very limited measures to open the door to both private insurers and private providers -- continue at a glacial pace, the NYT reports.
Posted by R.J. Lehmann on February 20, 2006 at 07:45 PM | Permalink | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0)
Wading into Wal-Mart's latest memogate over its efforts to control health care costs, Alex Tabarrok opines that the company is suffering from that most dread of insurance-related malladies -- "A.S.":
Wages for low-wage workers have been flat in recent years but health care costs have been increasing. For a company like Wal-Mart, which pays many of its workers modest wages but does offer a reasonable health insurance plan, this is an invitation to adverse selection. As the value of the wage component of the Wal-Mart benefit package has declined relative to the value of the health insurance component Wal-Mart has attracted more workers who want the job for the health benefits, i.e. sicker workers.
Though I may have trouble keeping many friends if I constantly subject their health care posts to nit-picky criticisms, I have to say I think the good Dr. T. is a bit off in his analysis, in part led astray by the N.Y. Times article that sparked his post.
Without question, Wal-Mart draws its labor pool from among the least desirable demographics, in a health care cost sense. Thanks in large part to a greater propensity for obesity, the working poor are disproportionately likely to suffer a variety of malladies -- high blood pressure, high cholesterol, Type II diabetes, acid reflux, hypertension, sleep apnea, respiratory problems, liver and kidney problems...you name it. They are also more likely to be smokers, more likely to be victims of violent crime, and have disproportionately more children -- leading to big bills both for obstetrics and for infant and childhood health care.
All of this contributes to what I'd call the "unfortunate selection" the company faces, but this is true of pretty much all large retail operations. The Times quotes Diane Rowland of the Kaiser Commission on Medicaid and the Uninsured saying that the company faces a disadvantage competing against retailers who offer no health benefits at all, but this is a radical overstatement. The number of retail jobs that don't offer SOME coverage is vanishingly tiny, by and large limited to those mom-and-pop operations that can't qualify under the federal ERISA law to be exempt from state-level benefits mandates. For those that are exempt, there is a tremendous advantage to offering compensation by way of benefits rather than wage salary -- both are fully deductible for the employer, but health benefits, unlike salary, are not subject to income and payroll taxes.
But to say that Wal-Mart's demographic problem amounts to truly adverse selection, one must ignore a rather crucial fact about Wal-Mart employees. That is, while most large firms that offer group health coverage typically see take-up rates (the proportion of those eligible for coverage who actually elect to purchase it) of 75% to 90%, at Wal-Mart, the rate is only about 50%. So, if the argument is that some large number of Wal-Mart employees sought their jobs solely to get access to health insurance....then why aren't they buying it?
To answer the question, it's important to keep in mind some other facts about Wal-Mart employees. Namely, that they are disproportionately likely to work two or more jobs (and thus draw coverage from some other employer source); disproportionately more likely to be women and/or "secondary" sources of household income (and draw coverage from their spouse's plan); disproportionately more likely to be minors or students (and draw coverage from their parents); disproportionately more likely to be seniors and/or retirees (and draw coverage from Medicare or a pension package); and, most crucial of all, precisely because of the very low wage rate at Wal-Mart, its employees are far morely likely than those at most firms to be eligible for Medicaid and other public health programs.
This last fact is the one that has done the most to engender public scrutiny of the company (and no small degree of public embarrassment.) According to a study of Wal-Mart's California employees by Ken Jacobs and Arindrajit Dube of the Labor Center at U.C. Berkeley, families of Wal-Mart employees utilized 40% more in public health care (such as that state's MediCal and Health Families programs) than did those of all large retailers. In response to such figures, the state in 2003 passed a "pay or play" health care initiative -- narrowly repealed by way of a Schwarzenegger-backed ballot referendum in 2004 -- that would have, among other things, defined the percentage of premium costs for which large employers would be responsible. Similar measures have since passed in Maryland and New Hampshire, and are gaining ground in a number of other states, helped along by big labor's ability to sell the notion to fiscal conservatives that -- with or without anything resembling Clintoncare -- Wal-Mart is already sloughing off its employee health costs onto the taxpayer.
And so, the company now increasingly finds itself between the rock of rising health care costs, and the hard place of government fiat, which the much-discussed "secret memo" from Wal-Mart's Susan Chambers to the company's board rightly recognizes is driven by some valid criticisms:
Healthcare is our most pressing reputation issue because well-funded, well-organized critics, as well as state government officials, are shining a bright light on Wal-Mart's offering. Moreover, our offering is vulnerable to at least some of their criticisms, especially with regard to the affordability of coverage and associates' reliance on Medicaid.
In total, the memo marks a brilliant strategy of counter-attack that looks to address both problems simultaneously. Moving toward high-deductible plans would lower costs to the company, lower premiums to employees, and likely increase take-up rates of the offered plans (and lower Medicaid take-up rates among employees.) As a sweetener to offset employee dissatisfaction, the high deductible plans would be coupled with HSAs for those who have been enrolled in a company plan for at least one year (giving the HSA benefit right off the bat would likely increase take-ups a little TOO much, and contribute to the rising cost problem.)
The 12-page memo, which I urge any interested parties to read in full, also offers a host of other strategies for addressing the company's labor and health care problems. Cutting cross-subsidies to spouses would decrease the job's attractiveness to older, costlier applicants, while making it easier for part-time associates to gain coverage (moving toward an average of one year for eligibility rather than two) increases its attractiveness to younger applicants. The company also would respond to employee demand for benefits that aid them in obtaining education and home ownership -- both of which not only prove to be more stable than health care costs, but also help attract higher income and higher educated workers, with more attractive health demographics.
But the real question is this: at what point do health care costs, and the relative unattractiveness of the low-income demo, combine to lead Wal-Mart to the seemingly counter-intuitive conclusion that the best way to control its labor costs would be to RAISE salaries?
Posted by R.J. Lehmann on October 31, 2005 at 10:35 AM | Permalink | Comments (238) | TrackBack (2)
Joanna Robinson over at Fey Accompli indulges in a bit of schadenfreude at the hands of human resources managers everywhere, in light of Kaiser's latest numbers finding that health care premiums were up another 9.2% in 2005, and that the share of businesses offering coverage to their employees dropped to 60% from 69% in 2000.
I was actually there at the Kaiser presentation yesterday, and they seem to take some creative liberties in choosing which numbers to highlight to the press. For instance, the press release makes great hay about the fact that average annual premiums for family coverage reached $10,880, thus eclipsing the gross earnings for a full-time minimum-wage worker of $10,712. That sounds quite terrifying, but it skips over the part where employees opting for family coverage were only responsible for 26% of those premiums, which was actually down from 28% in 2004. And, of course, any household whose head made only $10,712 a year would be eligible for Medicaid anyway.
Even the 9.2% number, it should be noted, marks a trend of flattening increases, down from 11.2% in 2004 and 13.9% in 2003. Hewitt Associates, for one, have projected that flattening to accelerate considerably in 2006.
That's not likely to cheer the lovely Ms. Robinson, who sees in these cost trends, and in the expansion of high-deductible options, a hope that the employer-based model of health care provision may finally be imploding:
High-deductible plans are a good transition to people owning their own insurance and being responsible consumers that demand good service and low prices - something that does not happen now with so many intermediary institutions keeping the system bloated and inefficient. If prices keep rising at the rate they have been, which I hope they do, it will finally provoke an actual market response.
I'm not quite sure about that.
High-deductible health plans, of course, are already widely available in the individual market, and in fact, they always have been. The newer and more marked trend is HDHPs coupled with Health Savings Accounts, which have only been available for the past year. The early evidence is that they, too, have had their greatest initial impact in the individual market, though Kaiser's lament that relatively few HDHPs in the group market are bundled with HSAs is premature -- the rules for the plans were only formalized this year, so H.R. managers looking to include the option would only have their first real chance to do so over the coming few months as they look forward to January renewals.
HSA/HDHPs are an interesting development but also, in my opinion, a mixed blessing. The "HD" part is promising, as it looks to return the concept of "insurance" -- that is, transfer of uncertain and potentially large risk in the long-term for the certain and predictable payment of premium dollars in the short-term -- to what is all-too-loosely called "health insurance." Were homeowners insurance to function the way health insurance does, every time you painted a room or changed a lightbulb, you'd make a claim on your policy. And you would only be allowed to shop at an Allstate-approved home improvement store...where non-members would be charged 10 to 30 times as much.
But are these products really likely to help bring costs down in what Joanna describes as the "bloated" U.S. health care system? At the margins, perhaps. They could reward some doctors and hospitals who lower visitation fees, thus encouraging investment in more efficient processing systems and procedures. They might also cut down on a few unnecessary tests, or lead consumers to comparison shop among diagnostic labs.
But despite the name, the deductibles in most "High-Deductible Health Plans" really aren't all that high -- $1,000 to $1,500 is typical for a singles policy. And, anyway, the HSA part of the equation would usually cover any of the common utilizations that the HD part would otherwise discourage. Furthermore, even if it did have the effect of curbing some arguably inefficient spending patterns, it's not entirely clear that discouraging "overconsumption" of routine health care is actually cost-effective. There are few markets more prone to "pennywise and pound-foolish" category errors on the part of consumers than in health care.
I actually would posit, contrary to the common wisdom, that rising health care costs are not due to the LACK of a market response -- rather they ARE a market response! What they are responding to is that we, as a culture, have a voracious demand for things that tend to make us sick, and for some medical means to deal with the consequences. Rising health care costs are not primarily the result of waste and widespread inefficiency -- they are the result of the ever-widening panoply of medical technologies created to address the trouble we create for ourselves. The cost of existing technologies is not growing -- it's falling, and impressively at that. But in the world of health care, there is always some expensive new gadget that enables some daring new procedure, and always a slew of Americans in line clamoring for access to it.
This fact of American life is rarely fully appreciated, in part because of preconceived notions (many of them held by Puritanical doctors and health care advocates) about what people "should" want from a health care system. Take this 2003 article from Washington Monthly, comparing American expenditures on health care with those of our amigos in Costa Rica:
TO GET AN IDEA OF HOW WILDLY ineffective our health-care system is, consider this: The United States spends roughly $4,500 per person on health care each year. Costa Rica spends just $273. That small Central American country also has half as many doctors per capita as the United States. Yet the life expectancy of the average Costa Rican is virtually the same as the average American's: 76.1 years.
How can that be? According to public health researchers, the biggest reasons are behavior and environment. Costa Ricans consume about half as many cigarettes per person as we do. Not surprisingly, they are four times less likely to die of lung cancer. The car ownership rate in Costa Rica is a fraction of what it is in the United States. That not only means that fewer Costa Ricans die in auto accidents, but that they do a lot more walking, and hence they get more exercise. Thanks to a much lower McDonald's-to-citizen ratio, the average Costa Rican thrives on a traditional diet of rice, beans, fruits, vegetables, and a moderate amount of fried food--and therefore enjoys one of the world's lowest rates of heart disease and other stress-related illnesses.
It's very telling that the author doesn't notice any of the corollaries embedded in the statistics he cites. Because of our health care system, and our surplus of doctors and technology, Americans can smoke twice as many cigarettes as Costa Ricans, can use lots and lots more cars to get us places, can gorge on all the tastiest fried foods...and still enjoy the same average lifespan! That is, in spending our health care dollars, the bargain Americans have opted for is to use that money to enjoy their lives rather than extend them. Where Phillip J. Longman sees inefficiency, I see rational choice.
So, no, I don't think uncoupling health care from employment is likely to do much to address the real drivers of health care costs. It would take a far more fundamental change in American culture and the sorts of things Americans value to do that. Moreover, Joanna's wish for a purely individual consumer-driven health care model -- common among libertarians, and a concept toward which I'm not completely unsympathetic -- runs into a bit of trouble when you start to game out how costs are distributed through the system.
Since I started writing about insurance full-time three years ago, I've come to have a deeper appreciation of what I like to call the American health care model's "dirty little secret." In her post, Joanna laments being uninsured, but the plain fact is -- for someone young and healthy like Joanna -- anything other than truly catastrophic-level health insurance is probably an irrational purchase. Even in an employer-provided plan, with your boss to pick up 3/4s of the tab, annual premiums, co-pays and deductibles are almost certain to far exceed one's consumption of covered health care services.
Indeed, were it not for the tax advantages granted by the IRS to employers to provide compensation by way of benefits rather than salary (together with the exemption from benefit mandates provided to large groups under ERISA) most people probably would buy their health insurance in the individual market. And were health insurers freed from state regulatory fiats that limit their ability to establish underwriting criteria (deciding which risks to take on and which to refuse), to determine which benefits they would provide and which they would eschew, and to decide how much they wanted to charge for different sorts of policyholders, health insurance would undoubtedly be cheaper -- far, far cheaper -- for the overwhelming majority of citizens.
Now, this sounds great, especially to a libertarian. But another Kaiser chart reveals the dirty little secret.
You see it? Yep. That's it. It's hard to believe, but our health care expenditures are so concentrated that just 5% of the population account for half of them, half the population accounts for nearly all of them, and the remaining half accounts for virtually none of them.
A further wrinkle to the dirty little secret -- for most, more than half of those costs will come in the two months before they die. Thus, for "market forces" to work their magic in controlling the driving costs of the system, we'd have to sit back while all but the most obscenely wealthy die because they can't afford the treatment that would keep them alive.
This is an intractable problem. You can play with the numbers and the various possible structures all you like, but it stays with us no matter what sort of system we opt for -- public or private, insurance or managed care, cash-and-carry or single-payor....you can't escape it. Most people consume no significant amount of health care. For those that do, the costs would almost always far exceed their ability to pay if there were no mechanisms to socialize those costs.
As it is now, we socialize the costs through successive tiers of mixed public and private payment structures. The old and the poor are both disproportionately likely to face high costs, so we have Medicare and Medicaid, both of which have moved toward structures -- like Medicare Advantage -- that allow mixing of some private insurance in with public subsidies.
Among the general population, we rely mostly on employer-provided insurance. Because employers -- especially large employers -- tend to draw from a diverse base of labor, and because the terms of group plans are the same for every employee, this further spreads costs on a relatively even basis, with healthier employees subsidizing sicker ones, and the employer itself subsidizing everybody.
For everybody else, there is a hodgepodge of very imperfect options. You can choose to purchase private insurance, but since it is usually irrational for young and/or healthy people to insure all but the most catastrophic of risks, private plans in the individual market will tend to face problems of adverse selection: the only people who will buy the coverage are those who either already need it, or who have a good sense that they will very soon.
Some states minimize this problem by creating high-risk pools, where those whose employers don't provide group coverage and who are too wealthy for Medicaid, too young for Medicare, and too sick for individual coverage can pay a little bit higher than usual for policies that are still mostly subsidized by the state. Where it's been done, this has helped limit adverse selection and made for a healthier individual market. But were it not for the fact that the overwhelming majority of those at "high risk" are already in Medicare, Medicaid, or group coverage, the risk pools would fall apart.
So, one way or another, those costs are going to get socialized. If it isn't through employer-sponsored coverage or some other distortionary third party mechanism, it'll be through direct taxpayer subsidy. Not many Americans would be willing to accept the alternative -- which is, essentially, to let the chronically ill suffer and let the terminally ill die.
And as committed as I am to free markets, I'm not all that inclined to argue that they should.
Posted by R.J. Lehmann on September 15, 2005 at 09:38 PM | Permalink | Comments (4) | TrackBack (0)
Recent Comments